Historical materialism as a sociological theory of all human relationships - The interdependent markets of capitalism
I:
INTRODUCTION
Historical
materialism (also known as “dialectical materialism” or simply “Marxism”) was
the method of analyzing social relations invented by Karl Marx and Friedrich
Engels, inspired by Hegel’s speculative idealism – it posits that each
socio-economic system that humanity goes through is made up of a certain number
of contradictions that create tensions that will eventually “snap in two”,
causing a revolution, moving onto the next economic system. It is marked
primarily by analyzing social trends by putting them in a historical context
and by the materialist viewpoint taking priority over the idealist
one. In summary: materialism posits that ideas, beliefs and ideologies are
created by the material conditions that the human lives in, while idealism
posits the opposite. An oversimplified example would be how an idealist could
say “racism causes poverty” while a materialist could say “poverty causes
racism”. Of course, in reality it is way more complicated and nuanced than
that.
In
this article I want to provide an extension of historical materialism by
extending our way of viewing “relationships” and “markets” to include the ones
that are not usually studied by most schools of economics, thus extending historical
materialism into a general sociological theory that makes us of all social
sciences: economics, sociology, psychology, political science – but that can
use the tools of philosophy and semiotics as well.
Marx was right on some
things and wrong on others, and since Marx’s analysis was primarily an analysis
of history that tried to detect trends and patterns in order to predict the
future, it will naturally fall under the limitations of any theory that
attempts a prognosis: the further in the future you try to make a prediction,
the more your accuracy decreases. This is why Marxism must not be abandoned but
revised (or “sublated”, to make a throwback to Hegel’s philosophy), in
order to take into account the newer discoveries in the social sciences as well
as to include in the analysis all the socio-cultural events that have happened
ever since his death.
The
premises of my theory are the follows:
1. Humanity
goes through multiple systems of social organization. Each system is like a
chapter in a book, a level in a video-game or an episode in a TV show, no
system is inherently “good” or “bad”, it is simply where we are at now. You
cannot skip systems just like you cannot skip chapters in a book, you must take
them in order. On one hand, each system of social organization relies on the
technological, scientific and cultural developments on the previous one,
therefore, it is impossible to jump into a system without first “finishing” the
previous one. On the other hand, the relationship is two-fold: once humanity
has “finished” a system, it must progress to the next system out of necessity.
2. Each
system of social organization has a certain “archetypal” form or pattern of
organizing all social relationships. Therefore, all human relationships
have a thing in common whenever they are put in the proper historical context.
3. All
human relationships are interdependent in an economic system. This means that
changes in one type of relationship will cause a change in all of the other
ones. My theory will attempt at being rigorous not only from a purely
theoretical/abstract and philosophical point of view (“logically consistent”),
but also scientific from the point of view of empirical evidence insofar as I
will try to give historical examples and case studies in order to prove my assumptions
(although to a lesser extent in this article, since this is only an
introduction).
II:
CAPITALISM – THE CURRENT SYSTEM OF SOCIAL ORGANIZATION
The current system of social
organization is based on the logic of markets and is usually what we
call capitalism.
All human relationships in
the current system are organized by the logic of markets: you are free to
choose anyone as long as they choose you back. Hence, the main ideological
concept tying together relationships today is consent.
The main form of
oppression in the current system is being indirectly pressured to give your
consent by the lack of alternatives, “circumstances” or “context”. The main illusion
is the illusion of freedom of choice. In capitalism, you are paradoxically
forced to “freely” do something. For instance, you are “free” to quit your job
if you don’t like the way your boss treats you, but if you do, you might not
find another job and you might starve to death, and therefore you are
indirectly forced to continue working “out of your own free will”.
Capitalism is divided into
multiple markets which are inter-dependent. Not all markets are analyzed by
economists, some are analyzed by other social sciences like psychology,
sociology and political science.
Each market has a certain
type of primary relationship.
Each market today has a
certain form of forming the bond of its primary relationship, each coming with
its own power dynamic. It is what I call “seduction” – by seduction
I am referring to changing another person’s desire. I am not talking
about seduction in the strict sexual/romantic sense, but I am talking about any
social process of changing what another person wants. Seduction is not about
giving someone what they want, but changing what they want in the first place.
It is a form of “soft power”.
Let’s give four examples
of the most important markets that need to be analyzed:
THE LABOR MARKET:
Its defining relationship is the employer-employee relationship (or the
employer – “potential employee” relationship, in some cases). The commodity
that is bought and sold on this market is labor. The seduction process of this
market is found inside the job-interview process.
THE GOODS & SERVIES
MARKET: Its defining relationship is the buyer-seller
relationship. The commodities that are bought and sold here are goods and
services. The seduction process of this market is found inside marketing and advertisement
of the sold-products.
THE DATING MARKET:
Its defining relationship is the romantic relationship. The commodities
that are bought and sold here are romantic partners. The seduction process of
this market is found in, well, “seduction”.
THE LIBERAL-DEMOCRACY: Its
defining relationship is the voter-politician relationship. This is the “free
market” of politicians. The commodities that are bought and sold here are
politicians and political parties. The seduction process of this market is
found in electoral campaigns.
Only the first two
markets are usually analyzed by “economics”, leaving the other two for other
social sciences. This is why I propose a theory of social sciences that extends
the idea of “market” to include more social relationships. Of course, there are
more markets and relationships than the four ones I’ve mentioned, but let’s
stick to these four for the moment.
All markets have certain
characteristics that unite them. They all conform to the laws of the markets:
supply and demand, etc. They are all marked by the ideological category of
consent – you are “free” to choose someone only as long as they choose you. The
power struggle is a struggle of “soft power” in which you convince the other
party to choose you over someone else on the market. The limitations and
oppressive mechanisms of each market consist in the environmental conditions,
circumstances and “context”: you may be indirectly forced or pressured into choosing
the other party by lack of alternatives, for example. Everything that I said in
this paragraph is inherent to the current system of social organization (“capitalism”),
and thus, next to nothing that I said in this paragraph applied to previous systems,
such as feudalism.
All markets have a
two-fold intervention with the state. In each stage of capitalism, the state
had a certain type of intervention in the markets, but at the same time, the
markets had a certain intervention with the state as well. The state intervenes
in the dating market with the regulations over marriage, or it intervenes in
the labor market through certain regulations, but so do the markets regulate
the state through lobbying, etc.
All markets and their
respective type of relationship are at least partially interdependent. The aim
of my method is to use historical analysis in order to give as many examples as
possible of how changes to the markets happen simultaneously: that is, a change
in the liberal-democracy “market of politicians” will cause a change in the
other three ones I’ve listed as well, for example. Whenever the markets change,
all four ones I’ve mentioned (as well as others I haven’t mentioned) change at
once.
III:
THE FOUR PHASES OF CAPITALISM
Capitalism itself is
divided into multiple “phases” or “stages”. Each transition between two phases
is marked by multiple revolutions around the globe all happening at the same time
and sharing a common theme (a “global revolution”, let’s say). I’ve identified four
phases so far, but this theory is prone to change and I welcome feedback,
especially since history is my weak point right now, having focused more on
psychology and philosophy until now.
The first phase of
capitalism is what is usually called “mercantilism” (cca. 1650-1800).
Note that some historians consider this as a separate system, different from
capitalism. I think it is fair to consider it the first phase of capitalism.
The transition from feudalism per se to mercantilism was marked by the glorious revolution of 1688.
The second phase of
capitalism is cca. 1800-1900 (the 19th century). The transition from
mercantilism to the second phase was marked by the French revolution of 1789 (which
quickly after spread around Europe), as well as the American revolution of
1763-1783, and the Haitian revolution of 1791.
The third phase of
capitalism is cca. 1900-1990 (the 20th century). The transition from
the second to the third phase was marked by the Russian revolutions of 1905 and
1917 and the establishment of the Soviet Union.
The fourth phase of
capitalism is 1990-present. The transition from the third to the fourth phase
was marked by the fall of the Berlin wall, the revolutions in Eastern Europe
and the fall of the USSR.
With each phase of
capitalism, you notice an increase in globalization. Feudalism was
marked by static, fixed, stable social relationships. The master-signifier of feudalism
was “land” and there was no such thing as fear of abandonment inside feudalism
since we can’t speak of the possibility of abandonment, the fear was the other
one: “I will be stuck with the same serf/landlord/spouse all my life”,
etc. Fear of abonnement can only exist in capitalism, which promotes social
relationships based on markets which rely on a connectivity between people at a
distance. To find “distance in closeness” or “to keep in touch at a distance”
is what we call in psychoanalysis alienation and it is not the same
thing as separation. Alienation is the primary defense mechanism of capitalism
and it goes hand in hand with globalization. The more you progress inside
capitalism, the more alienation and globalization increase.
Each revolution had a
major change to all markets of human relationships, including the four ones I’ve
previously mentioned. All four of those changed around the same time and around
the same way. Let us take a closer look at a concrete example:
IV:
THE FRENCH REVOLUTION – A CASE STUDY
The French revolution was
the transition from the first to the second phase inside capitalism, and thus,
it marked an increase in alienation. The more alienation increases, the more
the markets are “free” in the libertarian sense of “unregulated”. Alienation is
marked by connectivity along long physical or psychological distances.
Mercantilism (first phase) was marked by minimal alienation. We
can still speak of markets, but with very strict restrictions and little
freedom, we speak of local markets. Mercantilism was still a progress
from feudalism in which there were virtually no markets in the true capitalist
sense. In mercantilism, the primary policy was one of protectionism: the belief
in the static nature of wealth, the need to maintain a trade surplus (maximize
exports while minimizing imports), etc. Hence, the use of the “direct, brute
force” of feudalism was still used more than the “soft power of seduction” that
was invented by capitalism. The more you advance in capitalism, the more “hard
power” is replaced by “soft power”. Any phase of capitalism is still marked by
both since hard power was a marker of feudalism that is very slowly and
gradually replaced.
Hence, each market was “sort
of free, but not really”:
1. The
military intervened in the goods and services market to ensure that local
markets and supply sources were protected.
2. Family
heavily intervened in the dating market to ensure a similar control, that “local
markets” were protected from “outsiders” from various different social classes,
with the same logic. Hence why I nickname this phase “arranged dating”
in my previous books and articles, at it was a transition between the arranged
marriages of feudalism that were done for strict economic reasons and the “free
market of potential partners” marked by modern dating. In mercantilism, the
parents decided who you should marry, but they left their children to mingle
together under their supervision and they gave them some light freedom of
choice.
3. The
“free market of politicians” was also strictly regulated through brute force by
the state. Hence why in mercantilism (~18th century), a very light percentage
of people had the right to vote, but absolute monarchy was still the
primary form of government, without constitutional monarchy.
The French revolution marked
a simultaneous transition in all three of these markets in the same way. The
goods & services market was further liberalized and strict-protectionist
economic policies were reduced or abandoned in favor of the “lassies-faire”
capitalism promoted by economists such as Adam Smith. The dating market was
further liberalized and the exact same “strict-protectionist” policies of
parents supervising their children at dinner were similarly reduced or abandoned,
adopting a “lassies-faire” model of dating. The “market of politicians”
(democracy) was also liberalized after the French revolution, with the
introduction of a constitutional monarchy in order to replace absolute
monarchies.
V:
IDEOLOGY – THE MARKETPLACE OF IDEAS
To the four examples of
markets that I discussed above we must add a fifth market: the marketplace
of ideas. Under this market, ideas, beliefs and political ideologies are a
commodity to be bought and sold. I argue against the common interpretation
(John Milton, John Stuart Mill, etc.) of the “marketplace of ideas”, that
suggests that open debate and competition between beliefs on a “free market of
ideas” will usually lead to the truth – this implies that there is a
correlation between the popularity of an idea and its truth-value. Instead, I
argue that the most popular and mainstream ideologies are not the most “correct”
ones, but the most profitable ones. In other words, ideologies are a
commodity to be bought and sold and mainstream political ideologies are mainstream
because:
1. They
generate capital
2. Their
conflict generates capital
This is what makes this
theory “materialist” in the Marxist sense, that people’s ideas are caused by
the material conditions they live in.
We must argue against the
popular “immunological” attitude towards dangerous ideologies and
beliefs that we disagree with. The immunological paradigm supposes that bad
ideas are like a virus: they appear “out of nowhere” in a person, that person
tells his friends, his friends tell their friends and so on the bad idea
spreads like a virus. The conclusion of this way of thinking is that we should
treat dangerous ideologies like a virus as well, and this easily leads to
authoritarianism, censorship of ideas we disagree with, etc. I argue against
this – I believe this immunological attitude towards ideology is inherently
linked with reactionary thinking. We usually associate “reactionary”
with “conservative”, but nowadays we see reactionary thinking almost just as
often in so-called “socially progressive ideology” as well.
Reactionary conservatives
treat dangerous (from their point of view) ideologies as viruses that appear “out
of nowhere” and are contagious, infecting our youth and destroying our
civilization: “gender ideology”, “post-modern neo-marxism”, etc. Reactionary
liberals have the exact same attitude towards white supremacy, the alt-right,
Trumpism, etc. as if those ideas popped out of nowhere and infect our youth through
brainwashing and we must simply censor them (“quarantine the virus”). The
reactionary attitude, both in conservatives and liberals, is a message of “return
to normalcy” – they invoke a return to some pre-mythical past, back when things
were “normal”, to return to their “natural state” when things were “in balance”.
This pre-mythical past does not exist. Reactionary conservatives always talk
about “making America great again”, returning to “normality” in regards to “back
in the days when there were only two genders”, etc. Reactionary liberals talked
about returning to “normal politics” before Trumpism infected America, etc.
Both of these attitudes
completely ignore everything we learned from both Karl Marx and Jacques Lacan. Ideologies
are not only created but also sustained by market forces: the reason
such ideologies exist is because they contribute to the accumulation of capital
in society. There is something structural in society itself, some material conditions
that exist per se, that contribute to the development of ideology. This idea is
both Marxist and Lacanian in many ways. It is Marxist because it posits that people’s ideas are caused
by the material conditions they live in more than the other way around. It is
Lacanian because, like Jacques Lacan said, “the unconscious is outside”, “the
unconscious is structured like a language”, “the unconscious is the discourse of
the big Other” and so on. You can also find similar ideas in the philosophy of
Deleuze and Guatarri. For Lacan, you cannot separate the individual’s psychological
symptoms from the structural conditions in the society in which they appear –
if the unconscious is structured like a language, then the language and culture
in which we are born in can morph and shape the way in which psychological
symptoms and mental illness manifest. This is why the biological reductionism that
“mental illness is all in your head” is so dangerous. A banal example: a phobia
of airplanes couldn’t have existed before the invention of airplanes. So, if
you change something about airplanes, you might change the ways in which the
phobias manifest as well. Or, take financial anxiety: just like your individual
symptom of anxiety about your finances may say something about the society in
which you live in, just like that you can also analyze society and find
something about your own individual problems. This may seem obvious, but we
forget to do it in cases of more “abstract” psychological conditions in which
the relationship between society and individual is not so obvious: depression,
fear of abandonment, gender dysphoria, ADHD, anxiety, psychosomatic illness,
etc.
To return back to
ideology: let us take a concrete example of the marketplace of ideas. There is
an idea in the “dirtbag left”, the left-wing against intersectionality (which I
am also part of) that identity politics are a way to divide the working class,
such that we end up fighting against each other instead of going against the elite/bourgeoise.
This idea is on the right track, but the way it is presented is most often
incomplete: we must add that this doesn’t manifest as a conspiracy. It
is rarely the case that a bunch of rich people gather around a table and
discuss ways in which they can conspire against the working class in order to
increase their profits. Even in the cases in which it does happen, it is
secondary and only a by-product/symptom of the pre-existing material conditions
that would have caused a similar behavior even if they were to act
individually. What most often happens is the existence of what Alenka Zupancic
often calls “the invisible handjob of the free market” – the idea
that if every individual on the market acts selfishly, in their own interest,
the market will end up regulating itself in a way such that it will lead to the
accumulation of capital. Capital is circular and serves its own interests: wealth
generates more wealth, the rich become richer while the poor stay poor. This is
why leftists must not blindly attack Adam Smith’s idea of the invisible hand of
the free market. The proper answer is to insist that the invisible hand does
exist,
that there is indeed some truth to the self-regulating aspects of the
market (supply and demand, etc.), but the end-result is not that it serves the
people, but its own interests. It is like the Uroboros snake that bites its own
tail:
“Adam
Smith’s “capital” idea starts out from positing a social non-relation as a
fundamental state also on another level: as elements of social order,
individuals are driven by egotistic drives and the pursuit of self-interest.
But out of these purely egotistic pursuits grows a society of an optimal
general welfare and justice. It is precisely by ruthlessly pursuing one’s own
interest that one promotes the good of society as a whole, and much more
efficiently so than when one sets off to promote it directly. (...) What is
interesting about this idea in the context of our previous discussion is how it
takes a first step in the right direction and then stops short. To put it in
the terms we were using earlier, the idea is that what we find at the very core
of the most selfish individual enjoyment is actually the Other (looking after a
general welfare). What is missing is the next step: and what we find, at the
same time, at the core of this Other, is a most “masturbatory” self-enjoyment.
Adam Smith’s mistake is not that he saw the dimension of the Other possibly at
work in the most selfish pursuits of individual interests—all in all, this
thesis is not simply wrong: we never do just what we think we are doing and
what we intend to do (this is even a fundamental lesson of both Hegel and
Lacan). His mistake was that he did not follow this logic to the end: he failed
to see where and how the Other and its invisible hand also do not do only what
they think they are doing. … This is what becomes obvious with every economic
crisis, and became overwhelmingly clear with the last one: left to itself, the
market (the Other) is bound to discover “solitary enjoyment.” At some point in
his comments on Platonov’s “Anti-Sexus,” Schuster uses the expression: “the
invisible ‘handjob’ of the market,” which I am borrowing here, since one could
hardly find a better way of putting what I am trying to articulate. The
invisible hand of the market, supposedly looking after general welfare and
justice, is always also, and already, the invisible handjob of the market,
putting most of the wealth decidedly out of common reach. Adam Smith’s idea
could indeed be formulated in these terms: Let’s make the non-relation work for
everybody’s profit. And one could hardly deny the fact that what we consider as
wealth has increased in absolute (and not only relative) terms since the
eighteenth century. Or, as we often hear, that everybody, even the poorest, is
living better than two centuries ago. Yet the price of this modern economic
higher Relation is, again, that the differences (between rich and poor) are
also exponentially greater, fed by the non-relation in its “higher” form.”
(Alenka
Zupancic, “What is sex?”, Chapter 2.3)
If we now return to the
idea that identity politics exists in order to divide the working class, we can
now see a theoretical model for how such ideologies could develop. A lot of “anti-PC
/ anti-woke” leftists are slightly wrong in the way in which they implicitly
frame the causality of the relation: it is not that first we have the idea of
identity politics that was created by some conspiring group in order to divide
the working class. We must think in reversed order: precisely because
it divides the working class, the ideologies became popular. The
marketplace of goods and services “regulates itself” like an evolutionary
machine-learning algorithm: the “free” market of capitalism tries out multiple
options and whoever is the “fittest” survives on the market the most. This is
the idea of Adam Smith: the invisible hand of the market assures us that
whoever is most successful on the market is the one providing the best product
at the lowest price by virtue of the fact that everyone can try out multiple
options and the “bad options” in a competitive market will survive less. This
is also how evolution works: the genes which allow an individual to survive (natural
selection) and reproduce (sexual selection) the best will end up perpetuating
themselves further down the gene pool.
Adam Smith’s mistake is not
that this idea was too radical, it was not radical enough. Like Alenka said, he
took a step in the right direction. What survives on the market is not necessarily
the best product, but the product that assures the evolution of the
pre-existing market forces themselves. In this way, we can say that unregulated
markets suffer from a sort of “inertia” due to their inherent
contradictions (what modern economists call “market failures) that create
infinite feedback loops (example: see the Network Effect).
This is how we must think
of ideology in society. It is not how right-wing/libertarian thinkers think of
the marketplace of ideas in a similar way to the marketplace of goods and services,
that if we allow freedom of speech and open debate and competition between
ideas, the “best idea” will survive and become popular. And it is also wrong
how reactionary thinkers think of ideas like viruses/mutations that “appear out
of nowhere” and spread exponentially. There is a third way to think of
ideology, it is through the idea of the “invisible handjob of the market”:
ideologies survive because they are profitable and monetized, because they
continue the infinite self-perpetuation of capital itself. Hence, multiple
ideas are “tried out” on the “free market of ideas” and the ones who survive
are the ones who maintain the conditions of capitalism indefinitely. It is only
normal that the mainstream ideologies which survive in “mainstream politics”
are precisely the ones which serve the interests of capital the most, hence why
they survived. Thus, it is because identity politics generates capital
that we see it so often on both the left (“positive discrimination”, cancel
culture, political correctness) and right (nationalism, ethnic pride, etc.).
To take a cliché and a
bit edgy, but still popular example of how identity politics is profitable
on the marketplace of ideas, take a look at this meme:
We must think of
nationalism and immigrant fear-mongering (“right-wing identity politics”) as a
way to divide the working class – it is so popular because it can be
monetized by corporations and billionaires that can maintain their power. Multiple
ideas are tried out on the “free market of political ideologies” and the
political ideologies that survive and become “mainstream” are the ones which
survive on the market forces that spread and maintain these ideologies: social
media algorithms, advertisement, etc. We see the same problem in the so-called “left-wing
identity politics” in regards to, for example, the “wage gap debate”. In the
previous meme, replace the black worker with a woman and the white worker with
a man and the billionaire would say “Look at the wage gap between men and
women!”. This idea becomes popular/mainstream because it survives on the privatized
means of spreading ideas themselves (social media, television, etc.), these
means of spreading ideas being owned by those exact same wealth-hoarders.
VI:
CONCLUSIONS
To conclude: we have
looked at five markets that exist inside capitalism, only two of which are
analyzed by economics: the labor market, the goods & services market, the
dating market, the liberal-democracy and the ideology-market. My assumption is
that those five markets (and many more which I haven’t yet mentioned) are all
inter-dependent and my method employs historical analysis in order to fixate in
history the moments in which all five of those markets change “at once” and “in
a similar way”, me giving the French revolution as a simple example of
empirical evidence.
Questions for further
research/future articles:
-What is the way in which ideology
(the marketplace of ideas) changed during each of the four phases of
capitalism, along with the other four markets I’ve listed?
-What is the role of dogma in
capitalism, and can we say that in feudalism only dogma existed, while
capitalism plays with a mix of dogma and ideology (as Zizek defines the two
terms)?
-What are the ways in which all five
of the listed markets changed inside each of the four revolutions I’ve listed
in regards to the four phases of capitalism?
-What is the way in which popular
ideologies of sex and sexuality perpetuate themselves and become mainstream
because they serve the interests of capital? What about popular ideologies in
regards to love and dating?
-Has mental illness turned into a
form of identity politics and what is its relation to the factors of production
inside modern society?
FURTHER READING:
1. The politicization of sexuality – an article about the relationship between ideology and sex in modern politics.
2. Your money or your (love) life! – an article about the way love becomes a commodity to be bought and sold
inside capitalism, maintaining the self-perpetuating nature of capital (the
invisible “handjob” of the market)
3. The real, the fantasy of dating, of the obsessional and of capitalism – a more general analysis of how the dating market and the very idea of dating
is inherent to the idea of markets inside capitalism
4. The internet and the social life under capitalism – an article analyzing the relationship between the material conditions that
society (especially with the rise of the internet) is in and the way we view
friendships, relationships, abandonment, objectification, alienation, together
with the rise of dating apps, echo chambers and certain mental illnesses
(depression, ADHD, psychosomatic illness).
Comments
Post a Comment